Voiceover: In the last
video on taxing hamburgers, I did a somewhat artificial thing where I taxed hamburgers with an absolute dollar amount. Typically, consumption
taxes are a percentage of the actual price of the goods. For example, sales taxes might be 8% or 9% of whatever you are buying. Let's think about how the supply curve, as perceived by the consumers, would look if we had a percentage tax. Now, our government, instead of taxing $1 per hamburger, let's
say that their tax is, and I'll make it big just to
make it a clear, so we can see the result of it, let's say
their tax is 20% of the price. 20% of the price of the hamburger. Let's think what's going to happen. Just like we saw in the last video, in order for producers to even think about producing that first hamburger, they need to get $2 per hamburger for it, because that's their opportunity cost. Using those same inputs,
that same labor and resources their other opportunity
would give them at least $2, so you have to give them at
least $2 in order to focus on hamburgers. Every incremental hamburger after that, the opportunity cost goes more, because now they'll be using
things that are slightly less suited for making
hamburgers and maybe slightly more suited for making other things. Now, that very first
hamburger, you need to get $2 for it from the supplier point of view, but from the consumer point
of view, they can't just pay $2 for it. They're going to have to
pay $2 plus 20% of the $2. 20% of $2 is $0.40, so from
the consumer's point of view I'll do it in blue, they're
going to have to pay about $2.40. Right over here, if you
want to get the suppliers to produce about 2.5
million hamburgers per day, they're going to have
to get, especially for those incremental
hamburgers, in order to get 2.5 million hamburgers
produced, you're going to have to give $3 per hamburger for the supplier, but the consumer's not
going to be able to pay $3, they're going to have to pay $3 plus 20%, so that's $3.60, so that will
put us right about there. If you go further,
instead of $4, if you want the producers to produce right around 4 million hamburgers
per day, you'd have to pay them $4, but the
consumers would have to pay 20% more than that, so
they're going to have to pay $4.80. What you're going to see
is, from the consumer's point of view, the supply
curve, I should say, is going to look something like this. It's not going to shift a fixed amount up, it's going to shift 20% up. Let me do that ... It's going to shift something like that. For lower values, it's going to shift a less absolute amount,
because 20% of $2 is less than $20 of $3, which
is less than 20% of $4, so as we have more
quantity and more price, it'll shift up more and more, because 20% will then become
a larger absolute amount so the shift will look
something like this. At any given point, that is 20%. It's 20% higher than the
price that the suppliers and the producers would
see, so it's going to be 20% than $6 there, so this is
going to be $1.20 higher, but you have the same exact phenomenon that we saw in the previous video. In the previous video, this
entire area was the surplus that both the consumers
and the producers share. Now, the equilibrium quantity is less. It's going to move right
over there, because we have this new curve. Our new equilibrium quantity is over here, so neither the consumers,
nor the government, nor the producers are going
to be able to take advantage of this surplus, which was
there when you didn't have the taxation. This is why taxation is
generally considered inefficient. Obviously you have to do some of it, but it's generally inefficient. It reduces some level of
economic activity, at least if you make all the
assumptions in this model, and you have this dead weight loss. This surplus that can't be had by anyone, so you still have a dead weight loss. If you look at the revenue
that the government will now have, it will
still be this quantity. It looks like our equilibrium quantity is now 3 million hamburgers per day, which is about what we
got in the last one. Obviously I'm not doing
this very precisely, and it's going to be $0.60,
so 20% times $3 is $0.60, so the height is going to be $0.60. This height right over
here is $0.60 and the width right over here is 3 million hamburgers. It's going to be $0.60 per hamburger, which is 20% of its price per hamburger times 3 million hamburgers,
gives us $1.8 million per day and just like the previous one, now the producer's surplus has shrunken. The producer's surplus
is now just going to be this area right over here. The producer's surplus is
just going to be that area right over there and the consumer surplus has also been shrunken. It's been bitten into by the tax revenue and the dead weight loss
takes from both the producer and consumer surplus.