If you're seeing this message, it means we're having trouble loading external resources on our website.

If you're behind a web filter, please make sure that the domains *.kastatic.org and *.kasandbox.org are unblocked.

Main content

The Phillips curve in the Keynesian perspective

Read about how we can use the Keynesian perspective to think about the common tradeoff between low inflation and low unemployment.

Key points

  • A Phillips curve shows the tradeoff between unemployment and inflation in an economy.
  • Keynesian macroeconomics argues that the solution to a recession is expansionary fiscal policy that shifts the aggregate demand curve to the right.
  • The other side of Keynesian policy occurs when the economy is operating above potential GDP. In this situation, unemployment is low, but inflationary rises in the price level are a concern. The Keynesian response would be contractionary fiscal policy that shifts aggregate demand to the left.
  • Contractionary fiscal policy consists of tax increases or cuts in government spending designed to decrease aggregate demand and reduce inflationary pressures.
  • Expansionary fiscal policy consists of tax cuts or increases in government spending designed to stimulate aggregate demand and move the economy out of recession.

The discovery of the Phillips curve

In the 1950s, A.W. Phillips, an economist at the London School of Economics, was studying the Keynesian analytical framework. The Keynesian theory implied that during a recession inflationary pressures are low, but when the level of output is at or even pushing beyond potential gross domestic product, or GDP, the economy is at greater risk for inflation.
Phillips analyzed 60 years of British data and found the tradeoff between unemployment and inflation described in Keynesian theory, which became known as a Phillips curve.
The graph provides a visual representation of the Phillips curve with a downward-sloping curve.
Image credit: Figure 2 in "The Phillips Curve" by OpenStaxCollege, CC BY 4.0

Where does the Phillips curve come from?

The simplified aggregate demand/aggregate supply, or AD/AS, model that we have used so far in this tutorial is fully consistent with Keynes’s original model. More recent research, though, has indicated that in the real world, an AS curve is more curved than the right angle we've used up until this point. The real-world AS curve is very flat at levels of output far below potential—the Keynesian zone—very steep at levels of output above potential—the neoclassical zone—and curved in between—the intermediate zone. You can see these zones indicated in the diagram below.
The typical aggregate supply curve leads to the concept of the Phillips curve.
The graph shows three aggregate demand curves to represent different zones: the Keynesian zone, the intermediate zone, and the neoclassical zone. The Keynesian zone is farthest to the left as well as the lowest; the intermediate zone is the center of the three curves; the neoclassical is farthest to the right as well as the highest.
Image credit: Figure 1 in "The Phillips Curve" by OpenStaxCollege, CC BY 4.0

The instability of the Phillips curve

During the 1960s, the Phillips curve was seen as a policy menu. A nation could choose low inflation and high unemployment, or high inflation and low unemployment, or anywhere in between. Fiscal and monetary policy could be used to move up or down the Phillips curve as desired.
Then a curious thing happened. When policymakers tried to exploit the tradeoff between inflation and unemployment, the result was an increase in both inflation and unemployment. What had happened? The Phillips curve shifted.
The US economy experienced this pattern in the deep recession from 1973 to 1975 and again in back-to-back recessions from 1980 to 1982. Many nations around the world saw similar increases in unemployment and inflation. This pattern became known as stagflation—an unhealthy combination of high unemployment and high inflation. Perhaps most important, stagflation was a phenomenon that could not be explained by traditional Keynesian economics.
Economists have concluded that two factors cause the Phillips curve to shift. The first is supply shocks, like the oil crisis of the mid-1970s, which first brought stagflation into our vocabulary. The second is changes in people’s expectations about inflation.
In other words, there may be a tradeoff between inflation and unemployment when people expect no inflation, but when they realize inflation is occurring, the tradeoff disappears. Both factors—supply shocks and changes in inflationary expectations—cause the aggregate supply curve, and thus the Phillips curve, to shift.
In short, a downward-sloping Phillips curve should be interpreted as valid for short-run periods of several years, but over longer periods—when aggregate supply shifts—the downward-sloping Phillips curve can shift so that unemployment and inflation are both higher—as happened in the 1970s and early 1980s—or both lower—as happened in the early 1990s or first decade of the 2000s.

Keynesian policy for fighting unemployment and inflation

Keynesian macroeconomics argues that the solution to a recession is expansionary fiscal policy, such as tax cuts to stimulate consumption and investment or direct increases in government spending that would shift the aggregate demand curve to the right.
For example, in the diagram below, if aggregate demand were originally at ADr, showing that the economy was in recession, the appropriate policy would be for government to shift aggregate demand to the right from ADr to ADf, where the economy would be at potential GDP and full employment.
The graph shows three possible downward-sloping AD curves, an upward-sloping AS curve, and a vertical, straight potential GDP line.
Image credit: Figure 5 in "The Phillips Curve" by OpenStaxCollege, CC BY 4.0
Keynes argued that while it would be nice if the government could spend additional money on housing, roads, and other amenities, if the government could not agree on how to spend money in practical ways, then it could spend in impractical ways. For example, Keynes suggested building monuments, like a modern equivalent of the Egyptian pyramids. He proposed that the government could bury money underground and let mining companies dig the money up again.
These suggestions were slightly tongue-in-cheek, but their purpose was to emphasize that a Great Depression is no time to quibble over the specifics of government spending programs and tax cuts when the goal should be to pump up aggregate demand by enough to lift the economy to potential GDP.
The other side of Keynesian policy occurs when the economy is operating above potential GDP. In this situation, unemployment is low, but inflationary rises in the price level are a concern. The Keynesian response would be contractionary fiscal policy, using tax increases or government spending cuts to shift AD to the left. The result would be downward pressure on the price level, but very little reduction in output or very little rise in unemployment.
For example, in the diagram above, If aggregate demand were originally at ADi, showing that the economy was experiencing inflationary rises in the price level, the appropriate policy would be for government to shift aggregate demand to the left, from ADi toward ADf, which would reduce the pressure for a higher price level while the economy remains at full employment.
In the Keynesian economic model, too little aggregate demand brings unemployment and too much brings inflation. Thus, you can think of Keynesian economics as pursuing a “Goldilocks” level of aggregate demand: not too much, not too little, but what is just right.

Summary

  • A Phillips curve shows the tradeoff between unemployment and inflation in an economy.
  • Keynesian macroeconomics argues that the solution to a recession is expansionary fiscal policy that shifts the aggregate demand curve to the right.
  • The other side of Keynesian policy occurs when the economy is operating above potential GDP. In this situation, unemployment is low, but inflationary rises in the price level are a concern. The Keynesian response would be contractionary fiscal policy that shifts aggregate demand to the left.
  • Contractionary fiscal policy consists of tax increases or cuts in government spending designed to decrease aggregate demand and reduce inflationary pressures.
  • Expansionary fiscal policy consists of tax cuts or increases in government spending designed to stimulate aggregate demand and move the economy out of recession.

Self-check question

How would a decrease in energy prices affect the Phillips curve?

Review questions

  • What tradeoff is shown by a Phillips curve?
  • Would you expect to see long-run data trace out a stable downward-sloping Phillips curve?
  • What is the Keynesian prescription for recession? For inflation?

Critical-thinking question

Do you think the Phillips curve is a useful tool for analyzing the economy today? Why or why not?

Want to join the conversation?

  • blobby green style avatar for user Divya Garg
    The Keynesian view supports the existence of a downward sloping Phillips curve while the monetarists emphasize that Phillips curve becomes vertical in the long run. But is the long run Keynesian Phillips curve vertical, or downward sloping?
    (3 votes)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
  • duskpin ultimate style avatar for user cook.katelyn
    If people expect increased inflation, how is the Phillips curve likely to shift?
    (3 votes)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
  • aqualine seed style avatar for user Jackson Murrieta
    In my AP Econ, one of the problems we are doing is a fiscal policy action to make the current unemployment, which is lower than the natural unemployment, increase to match the natural unemployment. Which fiscal policy action would you use?
    (1 vote)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
    • hopper cool style avatar for user gosoccerboy5
      By definition, fiscal policy targets AD. The main 2 courses of action are to cut taxes and increase government spending. Tax cuts help the economy by less than government spending according to a concept called multiplier (see National Income and Price Determination), but either way, you may have to run a deficit. In other words, both are very useful, and they each have their own benefits. There are also other ways to decrease unemployment, such as decreased business regulations and lower minimum wages. In conclusion, the problem isn't very black and white, and you should visit National Income and Price Determination for more information if you haven't.
      (1 vote)
  • primosaur ultimate style avatar for user Alex Zimmerman
    Would you expect to see long-run data trace out a stable downward-sloping Phillips curve? Can anybody clarify this please? Thank you.
    (1 vote)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
  • blobby green style avatar for user shamitanathan
    What is the suggestion from Monetarist if we were to permanently reduce unemployment
    (1 vote)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
    • hopper cool style avatar for user gosoccerboy5
      The Monetarist school of thought actually suggests the opposite: that you can't permanently reduce unemployment. You can permanently increase potential GDP, but that's a factor of increasing productivity per worker. And if you visit National Income and Price Determination, you'll see why unemployment can't completely be reduced. If you are talking about monetary policy, that can't reduce unemployment forever either. Again, see Financial sector for information on monetary policy.
      (1 vote)
  • blobby green style avatar for user ambrosiaaa
    I was wondering how the business cycle is linked to the phillips curve. Can someone explain me how and why?
    (1 vote)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
  • blobby green style avatar for user Billie Patterson
    A Phillips curve shows the tradeoff between unemployment and inflation in an economy.
    (1 vote)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user