Main content
AP®︎/College Microeconomics
Course: AP®︎/College Microeconomics > Unit 2
Lesson 9: International trade and public policyTrade and tariffs
When governments impose restrictions on international trade, this affects the domestic price of the good and reduces total surplus. One such imposition is a tariff (a tax on imported or exported goods and services). See how a tariff impacts price, consumer surplus, producer surplus, tax revenue, and deadweight loss in this video.
Want to join the conversation?
- Why is there deadweight loss above 10 units at the end of the video? Why couldn't that also be part of imports and government tariff revenue?(5 votes)
- Assuming the US is a major sugar producer, if the US lowers its tariff on foreign sugar will that cause the demand for the dollar to increase in the Foreign Exchange market? It so then why, since price is not a demand shifter.(2 votes)
- If you are assuming that the US is a major sugar producer, lowering its tariff on foreign sugar would lead to a slightly lower price for sugar in the US. It wouldn't have any effect on sugar exports from the US to other countries. Thus demand for dollars would remain the same(3 votes)
- At, why is there deadweight loss on the inside of the region? Where did it come from? 6:05(3 votes)
- Why can't the two triangles be included as government revenue? (around) 5:23(1 vote)
- I think when you impose a tariff, it only affects the price of imported products, so it will raise the world price curve. But does the consumer trade at the world price? We still have a domestic producer who can supply at a lower cost, so the market price is not the world price.(1 vote)
- World price is still lower than the domestic price even after tariff. Domestic price is $3, and world price is $2(1 vote)
Video transcript
- [Instructor] In this video,
we're gonna think about how trade affects the total
economic surplus in a market, and we're also gonna think about tariffs, which are a per unit
charge that a government will often put on some type of
good that is being imported, usually to protect a domestic industry, but sometimes it's also to raise revenue. So, right over here,
we have a simple model for the sugar market in some country. And we're originally
initially going to assume that this country is
operating in isolation. So, this is the supply curve
for the suppliers of sugar in that country, and then
this is the demand curve for the people who would want
to use sugar in that country. And you can see the equilibrium price and quantity in that country. Now, in this world, we've
reviewed this in many videos, what's the total economic surplus? Well, the total economic surplus would be defined by this triangle right over here. It's the area above the supply curve and below the demand curve. And we know that the part
above this horizontal line at the price of three, this
would be the consumer surplus; and then down here, this
would be the producer surplus. Now, let's say that this market opens up to the world, to the world price. And let's say when it does
so, it does not affect the world price itself, the
world market is so large, and let's say this country's
market is relatively small. And so, the world market,
let's say that sugar is trading at $1.50 per pound. So, this right over
here is the world price, $1.50 per pound, let me
write it right over there. So, this is our world, our world price. Now, if we assume that it's opened up to this world price, what will happen? Well, at the world price,
the consumers in this market, the people who are using the sugar, well, they're going to use a lot more. At $1.50, the place where that intersects the demand curve is out here. So, now, what is the consumer surplus in this country, in this market? Well, the consumer surplus in this country is now much larger. It contains the triangle
that it contained before, and then all of this area
that I am now shading in. And that has come at the
cost of the producer surplus. The producers in this
country, or in this market, they are now only getting that producer of surplus right over there. But if you look at the total economic surplus, it has definitely grown. The total economic surplus,
instead of just being that original triangle, it has
now extended to include this entire area that goes
all the way out there. And you could see that
that completely contains the previous total economic surplus, which we had right over here. So, theoretically, when a market opens up to the world price like this, it's going to increase your
total economic surplus. And if that world price is
below the equilibrium price in your isolated economy,
then it's probably going to be to the benefit of the
consumers, but the producers are going to lose out on
some of their surplus. Now, let's say that a
government comes into power in this market, and says,
hey, I've been elected by the sugar producers of this country. I don't like this thing going on. Our sugar producers in our
country are getting hurt a lot, and they're a big voting block, so I am going to enact a tariff. And once again, a tariff
is a per unit charge, or it's oftentimes a per unit charge. And let's say the tariff
is 50 cents per pound, per pound on imported sugar. Well, then what is the world
price going to look like to the market that we're talking about? Well then, for the
consumers in this market, instead of being able to get
the world price at $1.50, they would have to pay 50 cents
per pound higher than that. So, the tariff would make
the price go over here. So, in that situation,
what has just happened? Well, now, where we
intersect the demand curve is a lower quantity than
when we used the world price. At the world price, we were consuming a lot of sugar in this market, and now we're going to consume
a little bit less sugar. But since, even with the
tariff, our price is still lower than our previous equilibrium price, when we were operating in isolation, we're still consuming more
sugar, using more sugar, demanding more sugar in this market than we were when we did not
have it opened up to trade. Now, what did this tariff
do to the surpluses? Well, the consumer
surplus has now gone down relative to the free trade scenario. We've lost this area down here. So, now, the consumer surplus, I will shade it in this blue color. And we have increased the
domestic producer surplus. It has increased to this, right over here. But what about this region that we seem, that seems to no longer be there, either in the consumer
or the producer surplus? Well, some of it is
the government revenue. What's the government revenue going to be? Well, it's going to be the amount of the tariff times the quantity. So, the amount of the tariff
is going to be that 50 cents, so that's that height right over there. And then what's the quantity that they're getting that tariff on? Well, this whole section right over here is the imported quantity. This section right over here
is the domestic production, and this is the imported quantity, so the imported quantity times the tariff, so this area right over here, that is going to be government revenue. But you do have some of
that total economic surplus that is just, becomes deadweight loss now. You have this region right over here that is now deadweight
loss, and this region right over here that is deadweight loss. So, I'll leave you there. As you can see here, that
when you open up to trade, theoretically, it increases
the total economic surplus. But that could have
consequences on the producers. And actually, there's
cases where it can have consequences on the users of whatever, or the people who are the
buyers in this market. And many times, a government
will enact a tariff. Now, you can see that that tariff will reduce the total economic surplus. Some of that will go towards revenue, while other parts of it will
just be deadweight loss. Another idea that a
government might sometimes do is an idea of a quota,
where they're saying, hey, we just don't like the total amount of imports that are happening, so they might just put a cap on it. I'll let you think about how
you might deal with a quota and how that might also
affect the economic surplus.