If you're seeing this message, it means we're having trouble loading external resources on our website.

If you're behind a web filter, please make sure that the domains *.kastatic.org and *.kasandbox.org are unblocked.

Main content

What is a free rider?

Not everybody who benefits from a public good contributes to its creation or maintenance.

Key points

  • A free rider is someone who wants others to pay for a public good but plans to use the good themselves; if many people act as free riders, the public good may never be provided.
  • Markets often have a difficult time producing public goods because free riders attempt to use the public good without paying for it.
  • The free rider problem can be overcome through measures that ensure the users of a public good pay for it. Such measures include government actions, social pressures, and collecting payments—in specific situations where markets have discovered a way to do so.

What is a free rider?

Private companies find it difficult to produce public goods. If a good or service is nonexcludable—like national defense—it is impossible or very costly to exclude people from using the good or service. So how can a firm charge people for it?
When individuals make decisions about buying a public good, a free-rider problem can arise—people have an incentive to let others pay for the public good and then to “free ride” on the purchases of others.
The best way to pay for public goods is to find a way of ensuring that everyone will make a contribution, thus preventing free riders. For example, if people come together through the political process and agree to pay taxes and make group decisions about the quantity of public goods, they can defeat the free rider problem by requiring—through the law—that everyone contribute.

Social pressures and personal appeals

In some cases, social pressures and personal appeals can be used—instead of the force of law—to reduce the number of free riders and to collect resources for the public good.
For example, neighbors sometimes form an association to carry out beautification projects or to patrol their area after dark to discourage crime. In low-income countries, where social pressure strongly encourages all farmers to participate, farmers in a region may come together to work on a large irrigation project that will benefit all.
Many fundraising efforts, including raising money for local charities and for the endowments of colleges and universities, also can be viewed as an attempt to use social pressure to discourage free riding and to generate an outcome that will produce a public benefit.

Why do people choose to be free riders?

The free rider problem can be expressed in terms of the prisoner’s dilemma game. Imagine that two people are thinking about contributing to a public good: Rachel and Samuel. When either of them contributes to a public good—such as a local fire department—their personal cost of doing so is $4 and the social benefit of that person’s contribution is $6.
Because society’s benefit of $6 is greater than the cost of $4, the investment is a good idea for society as a whole. The problem is that—while Rachel and Samuel pay for the entire cost of their contribution to the public good—they receive only half of the benefit because the benefit of the public good is divided equally among the members of society.
Contributing to a public good as a prisoner’s dilemma
Samuel (S) contributesSamuel (S) does not contribute
Rachel (R) contributesR pays $4, receives $6, net gain +$2R pays $4, receives $3, net gain –$1
S pays $4, receives $6, net gain +$2S pays $0, receives $3, net gain +$3
Rachel (R) does not contributeR pays $0, receives $3, net gain +$3R pays $0, receives $0
S pays $4, receives $3, net gain –$1S pays $0, receives $0
If neither Rachel nor Samuel contribute to the public good, then there are no costs and no benefits of the public good.
Suppose, however, that only Rachel contributes, while Samuel does not. Rachel incurs a cost of $4, but receives only $3 of benefit—half of the total $6 of benefit to society. Samuel incurs no cost, yet he also receives $3 of benefit. In this outcome, Rachel actually loses $1 while Samuel gains $3. A similar outcome, but with roles reversed, would occur if Samuel had contributed, but Rachel had not.
Finally, if both parties contribute, then each incurs a cost of $4 and each receives $6 of benefit—half of the total $12 benefit to society.
The difficulty with the prisoner’s dilemma arises as each person thinks through his or her strategic choices.
  1. Racheal reasons that if Samuel does not contribute, then she would be a fool to contribute. However, if Samuel does contribute, then she can come out ahead by not contributing.
  2. Either way, she decides she should choose not to contribute and instead hope that she can be a free rider who uses the public good paid for by Samuel.
  3. Samuel reasons the same way about Rachel.
  4. When both people come to the conclusion it would be unwise to contribute, the public good never gets built, and there is no movement to the option where everyone cooperates—which is actually best for all parties.

Review questions

  • What is the free rider problem?
  • Explain why the federal government funds national defense.

Critical-thinking questions

  • How do public television stations, like PBS, try to overcome the free rider problem?
  • Radio stations, tornado sirens, light houses, and street lights are all public goods in that they are nonrivalrous and nonexclusionary. Why do you think the government provides tornado sirens, street lights, and light houses but does not provide radio stations—other than PBS stations?

Problems

Becky and Sarah are sisters who share a room. Their room can easily get messy, and their parents are always telling them to clean it up. There are the costs and benefits to both Becky and Sarah of taking the time to clean their room:
  • If both Becky and Sarah clean, they each spend two hours and get a clean room.
  • If Becky decides not to clean and Sarah does all the cleaning, then Sarah spends 10 hours cleaning and Becky spends 0. Sarah is exhausted.
  • If Sarah decides not to clean and Becky does all the cleaning, then Becky spends 10 hours cleaning and Sarah spends 0. Becky is exhausted.
  • If both girls decide not to clean, they both have a dirty room.
What is the best outcome for Becky and Sarah? What is the worst outcome? Hint: It will help you to construct a prisoner’s dilemma table.
Explain what it is about Becky’s and Sarah’s reasoning that will probably lead them both to choose the worst outcome.

Want to join the conversation?

  • primosaur sapling style avatar for user Elado AO
    What is the answer to the second 'Critical-thinking' question? Is it that the positive externalities are so great that they outweigh any free-riding, whereas the positive externalities of a radio station do not outweigh the free-riding?
    (10 votes)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
    • aqualine ultimate style avatar for user Stefan van der Waal
      I think there are two reasons governments provide tornado sirens, street lights, and light houses but not radio stations.

      First of all, tornado sirens, street lights and light houses are pretty much mandatory for society to function properly. Radio stations aren't vital, so the government only does little effort in providing it.

      Second of all, it is possible for the market to provide radio since it can collect revenue from adds. It's impossible for the market to provide tornado sirens, traffic lights and light houses, since it's not possible to collect revenue from the customers.
      (22 votes)
  • blobby green style avatar for user Akshaya Balaji
    What is the answer to the Becky and Sarah problem?
    (1 vote)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
    • female robot grace style avatar for user Tiki
      By constructing a prisoner's dilemma table, it can be shown that Becky and Sarah both benefit the most when they cooperate to clean the room (They both invest 2 hours and gain a clean room), and are the worst off when neither of them does anything (No time is lost but the goal of cleaning the room is not achieved, and the dirty room stays dirty). The other options are that Becky does 10 hours of cleaning and is exhausted while Sarah does not contribute, or the converse (Sarah does 10 hours of cleaning and is extremely tired, and Becky does not contribute.)
      Similar to the problem about Samuel and Rachel, both Becky and Sarah would reason that if they decide to clean and the other does not, they would have to give up 10 hours and clean their room while the other does nothing - a foolish option. Therefore, each would opt to not do anything, in the hopes the other will clean, so they can get a free ride. Because Becky and Sarah reason this way, nothing ends up happening, leaving the objective not fulfilled, and a grimy room.
      (5 votes)
  • female robot grace style avatar for user 🅗🅐🅝🅝🅐🅗 😜
    From my own understanding, rich people who avoid taxes are also considered free riders, but nobody desires to do anything about that.
    Very convenient. -_-
    (1 vote)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
  • stelly blue style avatar for user Radha Patel
    So how can Patents and Intellectual Property Rights relate to this as well as Government Support with Research?
    (1 vote)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
  • blobby green style avatar for user Billie Patterson
    Shared responsibility is always best for both parties.
    (1 vote)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user