Main content
Microeconomics
Course: Microeconomics > Unit 7
Lesson 2: Monopoly- Perfect and imperfect competition
- Types of competition and marginal revenue
- Marginal revenue and marginal cost in imperfect competition
- Imperfect competition
- Monopolies vs. perfect competition
- Economic profit for a monopoly
- Monopolist optimizing price: Total revenue
- Monopolist optimizing price: Marginal revenue
- Monopolist optimizing price: Dead weight loss
- Review of revenue and cost graphs for a monopoly
- Optional calculus proof to show that MR has twice slope of demand
- Monopoly
- Efficiency and monopolies
© 2023 Khan AcademyTerms of usePrivacy PolicyCookie Notice
Optional calculus proof to show that MR has twice slope of demand
Using some basic calculus to show that marginal revenue has twice the slope of the demand curve for a monopolist. Created by Sal Khan.
Want to join the conversation?
- why is demand curve a straight line for monopoly?(3 votes)
- It can be, but doesn't have to be. It could be nearly any shape.(5 votes)
- Why is calculus so important?(0 votes)
- Like anything in mathematics you can go a long way with just arithmetic. Since math is built from more basic operations into higher more elaborate concepts (Khan Academy is based on this fact) you can do much with just addition.
So why learn multiplication if it is just addition repeated? 5x4 = 5+5+5+5. Awesome! I don't have to learn my multiplication tables. However if we do learn them we have the advantage of a short cut we know that 5x4 = 20.
Not only does multiplication allow a shortcut it also creates a new concept to think about the operation. Calculus is similar, it allows us to have short cuts and concepts that relate to rates of change, maximums of curves, areas under curves, and thinking about very small (infinitesimal) or very large (infinite) numbers.
In the case of this video knowledge of the derivative allowed me to understand the concept of marginal revenue right away because MR is a derivative of the TR curve.(16 votes)
- are there any activities or skill problems that go along with these microeconomics videos? if not does anyone know of a good place I can get some extra practice? (i'm an active learner so I need to do it to get it)(3 votes)
- wait why is MR the tangent of TR?(1 vote)
- MR is the change of TR at a given point which can be viewed as the slope of the tangent of the TR curve at that point. So MR is not the tangent of TR but rather the slope of TR.(4 votes)
- So what if the demand curve is not linear but exponential? Is it possible and will the slope of Marginal Revenue have twice the demand slope?(2 votes)
- No, this is only true for linear demand. Take this simple example:
Demand P = (Q - 6)^2 (exponential)
TR = Q*(Q - 6)^2
TR = Q*(Q^2 - 12Q + 36)
TR = Q^3 - 12Q^2 + 36Q
(calculus)
MR = 3Q^2 - 24Q + 36 (not twice the slope)(1 vote)
- In the starting of the economics playlist, we say that the quantity is a function of the price, then how can we compare P = Q + k (constant) to the general form of linear equation y = mx +c, because over here y is a function of x, but the price is not the function of quantity, its the other way round. Please clear my doubt, thanks :)(1 vote)
- We are not looking at quantity as a function of price, but rather marginal revenue as a function of quantity. Quantity is clearly the independent variable here: the firm chooses to produce a certain quantity and takes the point at which marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost.(2 votes)
- What can be inferred from this derivation? I mean what does it tell us in economics terms? Thanks in advance.(1 vote)
- It tells us that monopolies have the incentive to cut supply to below the equilibrium in order to get a higher price.(1 vote)
- Is this the case for Monopolistic competition and Oligopolies too? :)(1 vote)
- At, (TR)'/(Q)' what happens to Q? Isn't the equation wrote out just the deriveded of (TR)'? 3:30(1 vote)
- It's the derivative of TR with respect to Q.(1 vote)
- Why marginal revenue is half of the demand curve ?(1 vote)
- That is just how calculus works. Of course, this rule is only true for linear demand curves, not more complex ones.(0 votes)
Video transcript
For those of you who are curious and have a little bit of
a background in calculus, I thought I would do a very optional and when I say it's optional,
you don't have to understand this in order
to progress with the economics playlist, but
a very optional proof showing you that in general, the slope of the marginal
revenue curve for a monopolist is twice the slope of the demand curve, assuming that the demand curve is a line. So if the demand curve looks
like that, this is price. This is quantity. That is
demand right over there. I'm going to show that
the marginal revenue curve has twice the slope. It
is twice as steep as this. It's really twice the negative slope. So let me just write price
as a function of quantity. We know we get price. Since this is a line, we
can essentially write it in our traditional slope y-intercept form. In algebra class, you would write if this was y and this was x, you would write y = mx+b where m is the slope and
b is the y-intercept. I'll do something very
similar, but instead of y and x we have P and Q. So, if P = m x Q where m is the slope plus ... plus the P-intercept + b. So this right over here is b and if you were to ...
If you were to take your, If you were to take your change in P, if you were to take your change in P and divide it by your change
in Q ... your change in Q, you would get m. That is your slope, change in P / change in Q. Now what is going to be our total revenue? And this is kind of ... We're
just kind of almost doing what we've done in the last few videos, but we're doing it in general terms. So if this is total revenue, total revenue as a function of quantity. Well, total revenue is
just price x quantity. Total revenue is just price x quantity. We've already written ... We've
already written price as a function of quantity right over
here, so we could take that and substitute it ... and
substitute it in right over there. So we get total revenue is equal
to and I'll write it all in blue. We have mQ + b and then we're
going to multiply that x Q. We're going to multiply that x Q or we get total revenue = mQ^2. mQ^2 + b x Q And this is a parabola and
it's actually going to be a downward sloping parabola because m is going to be negative. This is downward sloping. m has a negative slope, so m is negative. So we know ... We know
that M < 0 over here. That's one of the assumptions we'll make. If m < 0, this is going to be
a downward opening parabola. Total revenue will look something, total revenue will look
something like that. That is our total revenue. Now, the marginal revenue
as a function of quantity is just the derivative and
this is the calculus part. It's the slope of the tangent
line at any given point and that is what the derivative is. It's the slope of the tangent
line at any point as a function as a function of quantity.
So you give me a quantity, I will tell you what the slope
of the tangent line of the total revenue function is at that point. So we essentially just have
to take the derivative of this with respect to Q. So we get D, TR/DQ. So how much does total revenue
change with a very, very small change in quantity,
infinitely small, infinitesimal change in quantity and this
comes straight out of calculus. m is a constant. Q^2, the
derivative of Q^2 with respect to Q is 2Q. So it's going
to be 2Q x the constant. So it's going to be 2m ... 2mQ. And then b is a constant.
We're assuming it's given. b is a constant. The derivative of bQ with respect
to Q is just going to be b. It's just going to be b. And so right over here, this
is our marginal revenue curve. or I should say our marginal line. It is 2mQ + b. So notice, it has the same
y-intercept as our demand curve so definitely starts right over there, but it has twice the slope. The slope of our demand curve is m. The slope of our marginal
revenue curve is 2m, is 2m and this is a negative slope, so
this will be twice as negative. So it will look something like this. It will look something
like this, just like that. So no matter what your demand curve is, if you assume it's a line like this, the marginal revenue curve
will be a line with twice the slope and in this case, it's
twice the negative slope which is kind of ... what's
going to be generally true. Anyway, if you understood that, great. You now feel good that this
is always the case for a linear demand curve like this. If you did not understand it, don't worry. You can proceed with
the economics playlist. You don't need to know
calculus for this playlist.