Main content
Microeconomics
Course: Microeconomics > Unit 6
Lesson 6: Firm entry, exit, and the shut-down rule- Shutting down or exiting industry based on price
- Long-run economic profit for perfectly competitive firms
- Long run supply when industry costs aren't constant
- Free response question (FRQ) on perfect competition
- Firms’ Short-Run Decisions to Produce and Long-Run Decisions to Enter or Exit a Market
© 2023 Khan AcademyTerms of usePrivacy PolicyCookie Notice
Shutting down or exiting industry based on price
A firm shut's down temporarily when it can't cover its variable cost, but it exits the industry for good when it's economic profits are negative. In this video, learn more about how to use a graph of cost curves to determine when a firm shuts down, enters an industry, or exits an industry.
Want to join the conversation?
- Why would price levels below average variable cost lead to immediate shutdown? Doesn't the firm stand to offset fixed costs by continuing to produce?(5 votes)
- Imagine if you bought a food truck, then realized it was going to cost you $7 for the ingredients for each burger, and the market price was $5. Making each burger would be a $2 loss, so you would not produce at all. This is a situation where average variable costs are greater than price.(6 votes)
- Does AVT always include the opportunity cost?
(I mean, if a firm is willing to produce at MC=MR, AVT = P, it means that they are breaking even and making financial profit, not 0 financial profit, right?)(3 votes)- No, AVT (average variable cost) does not always include the opportunity cost. AVT is calculated by dividing the total variable cost by the quantity of goods or services produced. It represents the average cost of producing each unit of output in the short run, which includes only the variable costs, such as labor and raw materials.
Opportunity cost, on the other hand, refers to the value of the best alternative forgone when a particular decision is made. It is not typically included in the calculation of AVT.
When a firm is producing at MC=MR (marginal cost equals marginal revenue), it means they are maximizing their profit. However, in order to determine whether they are making a financial profit or breaking even, we need to compare the average total cost (AVC) with the price (P). If AVT is equal to P, it means the firm is breaking even, covering all its variable costs but not earning a financial profit. To make a financial profit, the price should exceed the average total cost (ATC).(1 vote)
- what is a price taker?(2 votes)
- In economics, a price taker refers to a market participant or firm that is unable to influence the market price of a product or service. They must accept the prevailing market price as determined by the forces of supply and demand. Price takers have no market power and must adjust their quantity of output or consumption based on the given price in the market. They typically operate in perfectly competitive markets where there are many buyers and sellers, homogeneous products, no barriers to entry, and perfect information. An individual firm's actions have negligible impact on market conditions, so they have to accept the market-determined price to maximize their profits.(1 vote)
- How could it be possible for a firm's MR for every unit of output to be higher than it's MC (basically, for every incremental unit of output the firm is making more revenue than it cost them), but the firm's total revenue is still lower than the total variable cost?
They earned a profit on every incremental unit of output, so shouldn't the total revenue be greater than total variable cost?
Also, does the AVC curve not have to start off at the same place as the MC curve, since for the first unit of output, they are the same?(2 votes)- For the first unit AVC doesn't equal to MC, because MC is incremental, while the AVC is the average.
So, for example, a jump from 10,000$ to 10,400 as 40 more quantities produced from 100 would result in 10$ MC, while the AVC = 10400/140.
Because the MR which is also AR(average revenue)price is simply lower than of ATC, if you sell toy for 100$, but on average it costs to you produce it 140, then your Total Revenue will be less than Total cost(0 votes)
- Do any of these points change depending on if it's a competitive market or a monopoly?(1 vote)
Video transcript
- [Instructor] We've spent several videos already talking about
graphs like you see here. This is the graph for a particular firm, maybe it's making donuts
so in the donut industry, and we can see how the marginal cost relates to the average variable
cost and average total cost. We go into some depth several videos ago, but we see that trend, that marginal cost, can trend down initially
because as quantity increases each incremental unit could benefit from things like specialization. And then the marginal cost,
the cost of each incremental unit as a function of quantity could go up because of things like coordination costs. And then we've also seen
how that relates to average variable costs, that while
marginal cost is below average variable cost, every incremental
unit is going to bring down the average variable
cost, but then when marginal cost crosses average variable cost, well now every incremental
unit is going to bring up the average variable cost. And the same thing happens once it crosses the average total cost. And of course the difference between, for any given quantity,
between the average total cost and the average variable cost, that is the average fixed cost. Now with that out of the way,
we're going to think about how this firm would react under
different market conditions. We're going to assume that
it's in a very competitive or we could say a perfectly
competitive market and so it is a price-taker. And so let's first imagine
what would be a positive scenario for this firm. Let's imagine the price up
here, so let's call this P sub-one and in a previous
video, we already said it would be rational for
a profit-maximizing firm to produce at a quantity
where the marginal cost and the marginal revenue is meet. And if we're talking about
a competitive market, then this price right over
here is not going to be a function of the firm's
quantity, so that's why it's horizontal, and it
would be the same thing as the marginal revenue. So in this situation at P
sub-one, the firm would produce Q sub-one, and this is a
good situation for the firm because the price that
it's getting is higher than its average total cost
and so there is going to be a nice amount of profit for this firm. The profit is going to be
the price minus the average total cost at that quantity
times the actual quantity so because P one is greater
than the average total cost, we have a situation where
the firm is profitable, firm is profitable, it would
want to stay in the market but because you have a
profitable firm in this market and you're likely to have
many profitable firms in that market, it will
probably attract entrants. Other people might say, hey,
I wanna make just as much money as this donut
company right over here, than this firm, and so you'll
probably have more and more entrants into the market,
which will probably reduce the prices. Now they could reduce
the prices until you get to a price that looks something like this. So I will call that P sub-two. Now, a profit-maximizing
firm in this world would keep producing
until the marginal cost is equal to the marginal
revenue, which in this case is the price, and this would
be, my lines aren't completely straight there but you get
the idea, so that's Q sub-two. Now in this situation, P
sub-two is equal to the average total cost, so the firm is break-even. It's not running at a loss or a profit. So it is break-even and so
here the firm is neutral about whether in the long-run,
it stays in the market or it exits the market,
but you're no longer likely attracting entrants,
so no longer attracting, attracting entrants. But it does make sense for
the firm to keep operating at this situation even in the long run because it is at least break-even. Now let's imagine another scenario, let's imagine this price level. So for whatever reason, the
market price gets to that as we've talked about, a
rational firm would be producing at Q sub-three, and at P
sub-three right over here, there's some interesting things. Because P sub-three is less
than your average total cost, your firm is running at a loss,
it's running at a loss here. So running, so firm, firm not profitable. Not profitable. Now you might say, well what
is this firm likely to do, would it just shut down? Well in the short-run,
it would not make sense for this firm to shut
down because the price that it's getting is still
higher than its average variable cost, in the
short-run, the fixed cost, they've already been
spent, so you might as well get as much incremental profit
on the margin as you can and so as long as the price
is higher than the average variable cost, well outside
of their fixed cost, they're still making some money
to make up those fixed costs so you have two things going on. So they would stay
operating in the short run, stay operating, operating
in the short-run, short-run, but what would this
firm do in the long-run? Well in the long-run, it
makes no sense to have a, to be in a market where
you can't make a profit so in the long-run it
will exit, so it will exit in the long-run. And in general, the terminology
when people are talking about, well, do you start
or stop in the short-run, they usually talk about,
do you either shut down or operate in the short-run,
and then in the long-run, where it's like, hey, are you
going to sell your factories or somehow dismantle them
or are you going to build new factories, that's all
about exiting or entering the industry. And of course, you have
another even worse scenario for this firm, which might be down here, where you have price sub-four. Here, in theory, this
is where we intersect the marginal cost curve, Q sub-four. Now here it makes no sense for the company to operate at all, so
because P sub-four is less than the average total
cost, you would want to exit in the long-run, exit in
long-run, exit the market but you wouldn't even wait for that long, wait to sell your factories,
because P sub-four is less than your average variable cost, you would also just shut down,
shut down in the short-run. So big picture from a
firm's point of view, you obviously want to be at
P one where you make a profit but you might attract entrants. At P sub-two, you as a firm
in the long-run are neutral versus exiting the market
or entering the market or other people entering the
market, you're at breakeven. At P sub-three, in the
long-run, you'd wanna exit because you're not
profitable if the prices stay at P sub-three, your price
is below your average total cost at the rational
quantity to produce, so in the long-run, you would exit. But because P sub-three is
greater than your average variable cost at the rational quantity, you would stay operating in the short-run and then the last scenario
of course is P sub-four where the price gets so low
that it just doesn't make sense to even operate another moment.