Main content
Macroeconomics
Monetary and fiscal policy
Basic mechanics of monetary and fiscal policy. Created by Sal Khan.
Want to join the conversation?
- So I am confused. I am in a Macroeconomics class currently, and I am using Khan academy for studying, but my instructor emphasized how the Federal Reserve DOES NOT print money but that is JUST the treasury. She said that the Fed does monetary policy by adjusting the reserve ratio, adjusting the discount rate and buying/selling securities via the Federal Open Market Committee, but that its the treasury who PRINTS money. But in this video Sal said that the Federal Reserve prints. Which is right?(15 votes)
- Although the "Federal Reserve Note" in my wallet was printed by the US Department of the Treasury, it is issued and backed by the Federal Reserve Bank.(20 votes)
- When the government sells debt, how does it do this? The government lends to the banks? Or do they lend money to private citizens? Or both? What form of debt does it buy, is it just a loan, or is it some kind of bond?(11 votes)
- Not positive on this, but I'm pretty sure. :) I believe they "buy and sell debt" in the form of US Treasury bonds. As part of Open Market Operations conducted by the Federal Reserve, the Fed will buy bonds to implement an expasionary monetary policy (the kind you'd need in a recession to reach equilibrium), and sell bonds to implement a contractionary monetary policy (the kind you'd need when there is inflationary pressure).
Be sure to remember the Fed is the government's bank.(6 votes)
- So macroeconomics is the study of what? Money and various systems?(4 votes)
- Finance is the real study of money, while money is more of a unit of measure in economics. Macroeconomics is concerned with the structure and behavior of large scale markets (cities, states, countries, continents, etc); broadly focusing on Output, Unemployment, and Inflation. Of these three, only inflation actually studies money. I think of it as a back and forth study between how people's behavior affects the broad market, and then the opposite as well: how the broad market's reaction affects people's behavior.(14 votes)
- What is the Ratchet effect mentioned a couple of times in the last 2 minutes or so?(6 votes)
- The Ratchet effect: the price level tends to go up, but doesn't ever come back down.
This is not so much explained through Aggregate Supply or Demand, but just a tendency that economists have noted over time.(7 votes)
- Could someone explain the money market graph more please? I just don't understand why the money supply curve is upward sloping because in my AP Econ class we learned it was inelastic (a vertical line) and the Fed changes money supply as a measure for monetary policy to try and shift the AD curve.(7 votes)
- A perfectly inelastic MS line is the Keynesian economics model. In that case, the fed knows exactly how much money is in existence because they have a direct link to all banks in the reserve system. Therefore the fed can keep MS constant. If a deflationary gap is detected, national income falls below GDPfe, the fed will increase the MS through open market activities. By buying treasuries at a price banks cant refuse, the bank's MS increases. Banks don't want to hold this money because if they don't lend it they may have to return it to a reserve account. And if they hold it they don't make interest on it. Therefore they will lend it out, and through the fractional reserve banking system the MS increases, it is a money creation system. The fed does not print money, the treasury does. To deal with an inflationary gap, they will do the opposite.
These activities increase or decrease the cost of lending through the interest rate, and through fractional reserve banking money is created or destroyed, on a macro scale.(2 votes)
- Does this mean that the fed is always lending money to the US gov't when purchasing US treasury bills, notes and bonds?(4 votes)
- Are there any cases in which a government would want to use expansionary monetary policy but contractionary fiscal policy or vice-versa?(3 votes)
- Possibly. Expansionary monetary policy and contractionary fiscal policy would decrease interest rates (increasing investment spending), but roughly maintain real GDP and the inflation rate, since the decline in government spending reduces aggregate demand. This tries to change the economy's composition.(3 votes)
- After watching the video, I think I understand why the Federal Reserve calls what they have been doing "quantitative easing". They are increasing the money supply quantitatively, but they are not reducing interest rates, since interest rates are already at rock-bottom. Is this correct?(3 votes)
- I believe it is something else, that involves a ton of institutions and systems that is very complicated, but yeah, basically they increase the money supply, somehow.(2 votes)
- Government expenditure fiscal policy?(3 votes)
- Yes, government expenditure is a Fiscal Policy as it is a part of the Government Budget and Government Budget is "the statement of the estimates of the government receipts and government expenditure.".(1 vote)
- Since the federal reserve buys US treasuries, and the US government pays interest on these treasuries (over $.5 trillion in 2011), where does this money go? Who gets this?(3 votes)
- The money is payable to the holder of the treasury bond at maturity. If a bank (including the Fed) holds the bond it claims the money. The US government takes the bond back and pays the principal and interest. The principal is usually raised by selling a new bond, but the interest is listed in the budget. In addition to paying the operational costs of the system, the Fed pays fixed dividends to member banks. The treasury receives payment from the Fed for the printing of the notes the Fed issues.(2 votes)
Video transcript
Two words you'll hear thrown
a lot in macroeconomic circles are monetary policy
and fiscal policy. And they're normally talked
about in the context of ways to shift aggregate demand
in one direction or another and often times to kind of
stimulate aggregate demand, to shift it to the right. And what I want to
do in this video is focus on what these
two different tools who are, who are the
actors, and how do they go about actually shifting
the aggregate demand curve. So monetary policy--
this is literally deciding how much
money to print. So it's literally
printing money-- either deciding to print more
of it or deciding to print less. It tends to be done
in the United States-- especially in most
large countries-- it's done by the central bank,
which is sometimes directly part of the government. Sometimes it's
quasi-independent. In the US, it's a quasi--
The US central bank, which is the Federal Reserve,
is quasi-independent. And in future videos
we'll talk more about the governance structure
of the Federal Reserve. Most of the major appointees
are made by the US government. All of its excess profits
goes back to the US Treasury, so in that way it's part
of the US government. But it's set up to be--
also has some influence from private industry. The member banks have a
stake in what's going on. It often coordinates
amongst member banks. So you have your Federal
Reserve as a central bank in the United States. It's quasi-independent,
but it's been given the right to print money. And I'll just draw it
here as physical dollars, but most of the money that
is going to print actually is electronic money. And the way this affects
the aggregate demand curve, the Federal Reserve
doesn't just print money and go out and start buying
things with that money. Well, it does buy
things, but it doesn't go out and buy
goods and services. What it does with this is
it essentially lends it out, so it's essentially buying debt. And if buying debt seems like a
weird thing to say, buying debt it is the same thing
as lending money. If I buy a treasury bond,
so if I'm buying debt, I'm buying a treasury
bond means I'm implicitly lending that money. If I buy the bond directly
from the government, that means I'm lending that
money to the US government. If I directly buy a bond
from a US corporation, I'm essentially lending that
money to the corporation. They're going to give
me interest payments in the form of coupons,
and then they're going to pay back that
money at some future date. So this is essentially
lending money. And what this does is it's
increasing the supply of money that's out there to be lent. And so if we think of the
market for money-- so let's see, now we're thinking
microeconomic terms for the market for money. If this is the price of
money, which is really just the interest
rate as a percentage, and this right over here
is the supply of money. And I'll just draw-- so this
might be our supply curve. That's supply. And this is the demand curve. And let's say right over here,
this is short-term money. And we won't focus on the
different durations and all of that. But let's say we're
sitting right over here at a clearing
interest rate of 5%. So it makes sense. So this is right here. This is our demand curve. So all of the people who will
get more than 5% benefit out of the money-- maybe they have
an investment where they could get 10% on the money
or 8% or 5.1%-- they're all willing to borrow
that money and then invest it in whatever they want to do. Or this might even
be consumption, people who are saying, hey, 5%. That's worth it for
me to go out and buy that thing that makes
me whatever happy. But from an investment point of
view it makes even more sense. If I'm going to get an 8%
return on my money-- that's my benefit-- it makes sense
for me to borrow it at 5%. It makes sense all
the way up to 5.0001%. I'd actually borrow it. And so in the Federal
Reserve, or any central bank, prints money and it buys debt. It goes out into debt
markets and it usually buys the safest kind
of debt, but that affects all of the debt markets. It goes out and
buys debt market. They're essentially shifting
the supply curve of money to the right. They shift the supply
curve to the right. And so at any
given interest rate you could say that
there is more money. And so the supply curve might
look something like that. And this is interesting because
assuming the demand has not shifted, what you now have
is a different clearing price, a different equilibrium
price, for the money. Maybe this is now at 3%. And you also have more money
being lent and borrowed. So if this was the
old quantity of money that was lent and
borrowed-- I'm just going to make up a number here. Let's say that this is $100
billion in some time period. And now we're at $120 billion. So now by essentially printing
money, buying debt, increasing the supply of money
two things happen. Interest rates went down. And so now you have
all of these characters out here who before, they
weren't going to borrow money at 5% because their
benefit on that money was between 5% and 3%. Maybe it's 4% or 3.5%. It didn't make sense
for them to borrow at 5% and invest it and only get
a 4% return or a 3% return. But now that interest
rates have gone down, now it does make sense for
them to borrow the money, all the way down to someone
who has some type of project or investment that
has a 3% return. They also say, hey, I'm neutral. Now I could borrow at 3%,
and then I could invest it. But definitely the
person with 3.1% or 3.2%, if they have investments
that give them that much, they would definitely
want to borrow. And we could assume that all
this incremental borrowing-- so this little example that
I did right over here-- all this incremental
$20 billion of borrowing is going to be spent. People will borrow
money not to just sit but stuff it into
their mattresses. They'll borrow that money
to go invest it in some way, to spend it. And so what this
will do, all of this will shift aggregate
demand to the right. Right here, we're talking
in microeconomic terms, but then if we think about
aggregate supply and demand-- so this is aggregate. Let me write aggregate
right over here. This is price. This is real GDP. This is our aggregate demand. And then our short run aggregate
supply might look something like this. And so if we're shifting
aggregate demand to the right where there's going
to be more demand for goods and services, these people
are going to borrow this money and spend it. You're going to essentially
stimulate the economy. So this shifts to the right. You have a situation where real
GDP will go from this state to this state right over here. So it was expansionary. And obviously, if the
Federal Reserve decides to print less money
or if they even decide to essentially soak up
the money that's in the market by selling some of the
debt that they own, so that they're sucking
dollars out of it, then the opposite
effect would happen. Now fiscal policy is
essentially the government directly going out there and
demanding goods and services from the economy. You have the government. It has two sources of
revenue that it can spend. It has money from taxes. It has tax revenue. And then it can go
out and borrow money. And so it also has
access to debt markets. And when the government
borrows money, they're essentially
issuing treasury bills, if you're talking about the
US Treasury Bills and Treasury Bonds. If you were to buy those
from the US government, you're essentially lending
money to the government to finance their debt. And so they can take these
two sources of money, and then if they decide
to spend more-- and let's say that they're going
to hold taxes fixed. So they're not going to take
out any demand from the economy. They might ratchet up debt
and then ratchet up spending. And then this
government is directly going out there and demanding
more goods and services. So that could also shift
the aggregate demand curve to the right. So these are two different
levers, two different tools, that have been
used in governments all around the world to shift
aggregate demand one way or another or an attempt to
shift aggregate demand one way or the other. Monetary policy
is more indirect. Printing money, using that to
increase the supply of money that's out there to be lent,
that lowers interest rates. And then because it
lowers interest rates, there's more willingness to
borrow and invest that money. Fiscal policy, you're directly
going out there and just buying more goods and services
by usually ratcheting up your debt. Or fiscal policy could
go the other way. If you're trying to restrain
the economy, you could lower your debt, lower
your spending, or you could do some other
combination. s