- When you think about what the
field of economics is about, it is quite daunting. An economy is made up of millions
or even billions of actors organized in incredibly complex ways. Write down, this is complex real-world and each of the actors, human
beings or organizations, these are incredibly complex. A human brain. I can't predict what you're
going to do the next second much less what you're going to do the next day or the next year and imagine trying to make insights about what millions or
billions of people will do but the field of economics
has borrowed an idea from other fields. So for example, in chemistry, chemists have tried to
understand at a high level, well, how do molecules
in a container behave? Let's say molecules of gas. Well, you could imagine if
you have a container here with trillions upon
trillions of molecules, this is incredibly complex but by making some simplifying assumptions about the type of interactions
these particles will have or don't have, they
can come up with models like the ideal gas law which
you might be familiar with or not from your chemistry class that relates the pressure to the volume to the number of particles you have to the actual temperature and so this right over here where you're taking something
that's hairy and complex and making simplifying assumptions to help you understand it, this thing right over here is a model and this is in other fields as well. Sometimes, it's not an equation. Sometimes, it might be a simpler organism. For example, in biology, human beings are incredibly
complex organisms and not only are they incredibly complex but certain forms of experimentation would also feel fairly unethical
to our modern moral ethos and so what do biologists do? Well, they make simplifying
assumptions or they pare down, they say, okay, we can't do
that study on human beings but maybe we can simplify the problem by looking at simpler organisms. Maybe you can look at an
individual cell right over here. Maybe you can look at
things like fruit flies which are famous in the study of genetics. Maybe you can even look at
fairly complex organisms. Even a mouse is a very complex thing but it's still simpler than a human being and at least to our modern ethics, we're willing to do certain things to mice that we aren't willing
to do to human beings and so that's why in a biological context, you will hear people talk
about things like a mouse model where they will test a drug on a mouse or try to understand how
something happens in a mouse and then say, well, that's
a pretty good indication that might be happening to human beings. In fact, when they do
drug trials in medicine, they often will do it on mice first and when they have good
confidence that it works there and that it's fairly safe, only then will they start
to do the experiments on human beings. Well, economists are doing the same thing. Even before the advent of
computers and computer models, economists make simplifying assumptions, assumptions like all of
the actors in an economy are rational which we already
know is not exactly true. I'm not always rational and I definitely know people
who aren't always rational. They're simplifying assumptions that all of the people in an economy have the same access to information or that they all even
have perfect information which we also know isn't
necessarily true in a real economy. So depending on the model, there are going to be these
simplifying assumptions that take this large,
complex real-world thing and try to break it down
into simple equations or lines or charts. We have models early on
in our economic study. We will see things like the
production possibility frontier where it assumes that
you're only trading off between two things and
everything else is equal, this notion of ceteris, ceteris paribus which means all things equal. In a real-world, you're
not gonna be able to say, hey, let's just pick
between these two things and then hold everything else equal. There's hundreds or thousands or millions of variables are operating but if you wanna make a model, maybe we can make these assumptions. Same thing with famous price equilibria that we're going to study later on where you have supply and demand and then you have these notions of equilibrium prices and quantities. These also make similar
types of assumptions about rational actors
and perfect information and these economic
models can be very useful and that's why most of your study in a first year economics
course is of these models. Now, with that said, you should also take
them with a grain of salt and you shouldn't just accept them as the absolute description of reality. In fact, that's when economic
models can get dangerous. You always have to be conscientious of what are those assumptions you made? In fact, Nobel Prizes
have been won in economics by revisiting some simplifying assumptions and coming up with new models. The other difficulty about economics is it's hard to test
it in as absolute a way definitely as something
like chemistry or physics but even in biology where you're dealing with
similarly complex systems, a human body and an economy, these are both extremely complex systems. If I wanna see in medicine whether a certain medication works, I can do a clinical trial. I could take hundreds
or thousands of people and give maybe half of them the drug and I could try to control for a bunch of different variables but in economics, you can't take a thousand
different economies that look very similar
in what you think matters and then apply some type
of economic prescription to half of them and then see what happens, to see whether your model is exactly true or whether your prescription for what makes an economy
grow faster actually works and so the big takeaway, models are valuable across
the various sciences including in economics but economics straddles
between a social science and the sciences like chemistry or physics because you can't run
experiments in the same way and we often make simplifying assumptions that even though we know
aren't exactly true, they're the only way that
we're able to make sense of an incredibly complex real-world.