Main content
Macroeconomics
Keynesian cross
Analyzing planned expenditures versus actual output using the Keynesian Cross. Created by Sal Khan.
Want to join the conversation?
- Okay, I may be overlooking or forgetting something major here, but I don't get how this Keynesian cross and its equation is even possible. I thought C+I+G+NX was the expenditure approach to calculating GDP. But this equation presents aggregate expenditure as a function of aggregate income! Since the Y (aggregate income) here is equivalent to real GDP, shouldn't E=Y at all times? I thought what E and Y represent are just two different approaches to calculating the same thing, namely GDP.(8 votes)
- As you so rightly mentioned, actual expenditure will always equal output, since they are two sides of the same coin (my expenditure is going to be somebody else's income). However, note that (investment) expenditure also includes increase in inventories. So there could be a case where, as is mentioned in the video, actual expenditure equals output only due to an inventory build-up.
Using a more common sense approach, even in separate markets (microeconomics), there is a possibility where the market may not be in equilibrium, leading to excess demand or excess supply. In that case, through the price mechanism, the market once again moves back to equilibrium, just as the case is here.(9 votes)
- So how is the keynesian cross different from using aggregate supply and demand?(9 votes)
- So what does it Keynesian cross model mean at all?(1 vote)
- I'm getting confused with the word choice here. How would we know with certainty what people's PLANNED expenditures are? Or the government's PLANNED expenditures? Wouldn't all we really know be what they ACTUALLY bought or consumed? Why not just call this expenditures?(6 votes)
- You would never know "with certainty" what the aggregate planned expenditures are for a country. These little models are just ways to help you get your head around big ideas. You can't take them too seriously, or you'll just get painted into a corner.
However, planned expenditures for a company are sometimes somewhat known (at least by that company) - they have some sense of their budget for the upcoming year normally. (Though plans often wildly change.)(6 votes)
- How do you find the equilibrium level?(4 votes)
- The equilibrium level is where the expenditure equals what is produced, which is the output (Y). Thus the intersection point of the planned expenditure function and the output function is the equilibrium.(3 votes)
- So, basically, in the equilibrium point Spending = Income? So there's no net savings?(3 votes)
- No, there is no net savings. If there were ever more savings than borrowing, the interest rate would go down, making the quantity of saving decrease and the quantity of borrowing increase. If there were ever more borrowing than saving, the interest rate would increase, which would increase the quantity of saving and decrease the quantity of borrowing.(3 votes)
- This may be a bit off-topic, but how come there are no videos on supply-side economics (especially when dealing with the Laffer curve)? I know supply-side economics has its critics (me included), but I think they would add more to the discussion on different ways of economic thinking.(3 votes)
- How come Y denotes income and also GDP or output?(2 votes)
- what is difference between equilibrium level of output and income level in keynsian and classical models.?(2 votes)
- Does this imply that, given that MPC is the slope of consumption function, that the value of MPC at which the inverse tangent (MPC) = 45 degrees would be the ideal consumption for an economy? If this is the case, does the Keynesian cross support the idea that the ideal consumption for an economy in perpetual stability would be at MPC = 1?(2 votes)
- No, if the MPC=1 then the slope of the planned expenditure curve is also 1 and it would be above the equilibrium line where Planned Expenditure = Aggregate Income. This is an impossible state as you cannot keep expending at a higher rate than income (or output).(1 vote)
- Ok. Do the firms sell all their inventories and cut production when income is above equilibrium and increase production and use inventories when the income is below equilibrium because the y want to get back to good business where they actually make good sales as expected ?(1 vote)
- Yes, that is the purpose of inventories. They are selling their products later, when they underproduce rather than overproduce.(1 vote)
Video transcript
What I want to introduce
you to in this video is the idea of a Keynesian Cross. This is one of the tools of
analysis of Keynesian thinking which is really the idea
that maybe every now and then the GDP, when it's at equilibrium, isn't at an optimal state. It's operating well below potential and the way that we might be able to get. If you are a follower
of Keynesian thinking, the way that we can get it closer to, potential closer to full employment is by somehow affecting
aggregate demand in some way. What we'll see is, we're going to build up our
Keynesian Cross analysis based on what we understand
from the consumption function. We're going to first start thinking about planned expenditures. We're going to think about what happens when planned expenditures
deviates from actual output, from actual expenditures, right over here. This is very similar to
what we're done before but we're actually thinking
of it in terms of planning. Let's say we have planned expenditures, expenditures planned and we could just write the components of aggregate expenditure here. Well, you're going to
have consumer spending, you're going to have investment. I'm going to be careful here, I'm going to call it planned investment. This is exactly what firms
are looking to produce. The reason why I differentiate this here is because, if for whatever reason, aggregate expenditure
is less than they expect then they might build up inventories and those inventories get
counted as investments. Those would be excess
inventories above and beyond the planned inventories. If actual demand is higher than expended then it might eat in to inventories and when inventories are eaten into it actually takes away
from planned investments there would actually be kind of a, you would be eating into
the total investment in that situation. That's why I'm going to differentiate between planned investment
and actual investment. Then of course, you
have government spending and then finally you have net exports. For the sake of the analysis
of the Keynesian Cross, once again, this is a
super over simplification, we're going to assume that
at any given level of GDP or aggregate output that
these are all constant. That these are not really dependent on aggregate output or GDP which is of course a
huge over simplification. If we were to plot any of these versus aggregate income we'd say that they are really a flat line. Maybe planned investment might
look something like that. Maybe government spending
would look something like that. No ways at some level that's preplanned, it's exogenous to our model. It's not dependant in any way. It's an external factor. Assuming it's fixed, it's not dependent on aggregate income. So government spending
looks something like that and net exports, maybe it
looks something like that. The one factor that you can imagine because I said we're going to build on top of the consumption function that we're going to assume
is driven by aggregate income is consumption right over here. The way that this thing will look, the way that this thing will look is you have ... So let me draw another
plot right over here, draw another plot. We have aggregate income, that is going to be our
independent variable and then over here we can
just view this as expenditure. If we were just to plot consumer spending, we've seen that before especially if we assume a
linear consumption function. What we've studied in the last few videos is all linear consumption functions and depending on how you write it, but they all look something like this. They have a positive
vertical axis intercept and they have upward
slope that is less than 1. Consumption by itself would
look something like this, this would be consumer spending as a function of aggregate income. Then if you all all of
these constants to it then your graph for aggregate
planned expenditures would look something like this. if you added just in net exports it would get a little bit higher because these are constant. Any point you would add this much, if you add government a
little higher than that and if you add all of them
including planned investments you might get something that looks, and I'll do it in this
color right over here, you might get something
that looks like this. I'm just starting off
with consumer spending. I'm using a linear consumption function, you don't have to, but it makes the Keynesian Cross analysis a lot more cross like
and easier to analyse. If you add all what we
assumed to be constant things and aggregate expenditures
is going to be up here. This right over here is aggregate planned
expenditures I should say. Now, we know from the
circular flow in the economy that when an economy is at equilibrium, your aggregate output is equal
to your aggregate expenditures or your aggregate expenditures is equal to your aggregate income. Really, at an equilibrium, these two things are going to be equal. We can actually plot a line
that shows all the points that those are equal. That would be a line that
has essentially a slope of 1 where Y is always equal to expenditures. It might look something like this. This is where the name
Keynesian cross comes from because essentially you
have planned expenditures and then right over here you
have the equilibrium line or what I call the equilibrium line because these are all points where income is equal to expenditure. Right over here, income
is equal to expenditure. Income is equal to expenditure. When you look at aggregate
planned expenditures or you can even view
this as aggregate demand as a function of aggregate income. This is actual point where the actual economy is at equilibrium where expenditures are actually equal to, where expenditures are
actually equal to output. Actually, it's a little bit
skewed the way I drew it but these actually
should be like a square. Actually, let me see if
I can draw a little bit clearer than that. Just so it will actually
looks like a 45 degree line. It should really be a 45
degree line like that. That seems a little bit better. That's the point at which
we are at equilibrium. Actually, I don't like that because it makes it a little
bit harder to analyse. But hopefully you get the idea. This should be a line
that's where expenditures is equal to aggregate income. Like this so it intersects at a point that's a little bit
easier for me to analyse. Now, this is where the Keynesian Cross becomes a kind of interesting tool because we could start to think about what happens in situations. This is an equilibrium level of GDP. What happens if for whatever reason that aggregate income is higher than that equilibrium level? Let's think about scenario. Let's say we're over here. Let me do that in magenta. Let's say we're over here. Let's call that Y1. What is going on? What is going on right over here at Y1? Over here, the aggregate output which is the same thing
as aggregate income is right over here. Well, this is the actually
planned expenditures, is right over here. All of these excess. All of these excess above the planned demand, these are essentially going
to be inventories building up. The economy is producing
more than it actually needs, inventories are going to build up. Firms are not selling
all of their products and that excess built up inventory is going to be reflected in investment. In this case, this delta. This delta is going to be added
to your planned investment to get what the actual
investment might be. When an economy is at that state then firms would say, "Oh my god! "We're building inventory
more than we expected. "We're not selling our products. "We're going to lower output "so there's a natural
feedback mechanism for the GDP "to go back to equilibrium." Let's think about what happens if it's below that equilibrium point. Let's say that GDP is, let's call that right over here. This is Y2. Actually, I could write it as a subscript. I don't know, I wrote a superscript there. We could call this Y2. Over here, aggregate demand
at this level of output is more than what's actually being output. People want more goods and services. Right over here, this is a deficit of output and so this shows that people will be digging into inventory. That the existing inventories or the existing investment was not enough. Or, I guess another way to think it, essentially, inventories
will be contracting. Let's say business was constant. I had a lemonade stand,
I just keep an inventory of 5 cups of lemonade on hand and I sell a cup every hour. If all of a sudden people
start buying 2 cups an hour my inventory is going to
start getting depleted and so this is what's reflected. Actual output is below what's demanded. When firms start seeing that their inventories
get depleted, they say, "Oh my god! "I don't want to run out
of my goods and services. "Let me start producing more." Then when we're talking about inventories we're really talking about goods. So let me produce more. So output will once again want to naturally go
to that feedback point. Hopefully that makes
a little bit of sense. In the next few videos we'll
be using the Keynesian Cross to think about the
Keynesian line of reasoning. If you change one of these, how that might affect the
new equilibrium level of GDP.