If you're seeing this message, it means we're having trouble loading external resources on our website.

If you're behind a web filter, please make sure that the domains *.kastatic.org and *.kasandbox.org are unblocked.

Main content

Indifference curves and marginal rate of substitution

We can graph how we value tradeoffs between two goods. Created by Sal Khan.

Want to join the conversation?

  • leaf green style avatar for user Ankit Agrawal
    Are Opportunity cost and Rate of substitution same ?
    (14 votes)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
    • male robot hal style avatar for user Enn
      Opportunity cost is the cost of the next best alternative given up or sacrificed.
      The Marginal Rate of Substitution is the amount of of a good that has to be given up to obtain an additional unit of another good while keeping the satisfaction the same. As some amount of a good has to be sacrificed for an additional unit of another good it is the Opportunity Cost.
      The MRS is basically a way of mathematically representing the opportunity cost of getting an additional unit of some good.
      The MRS only gives the opportunity cost of getting a additional unit of a good.
      Opportunity cost itself is a wider concept like if a person has a choice of either being a farmer or a shopkeeper and the person becomes a farmer then the opportunity cost is the chance of being a shopkeeper.
      (29 votes)
  • leaf green style avatar for user abhishek gupta
    what is difference between marginal rate of exchange and marginal rate of substitution?
    (16 votes)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
    • leaf green style avatar for user Joonas Valkama
      MRS describes a substitution between two goods. MRS changes from person to person, as it depends on an individual's subjective preferences.

      Marginal Rate of Exchange, on the other hand, describes the price ratio of two goods relative to each other. It does not depend on an individual preference, but is determined by the market, hence the same MRE applies to everyone.
      (46 votes)
  • blobby green style avatar for user Minhaj Hussain
    Why two Indifference curves cannot intersect each other?
    (7 votes)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
    • old spice man green style avatar for user Mtr
      Each curve represents a set of combinations of goods that give a specific level of utility. Different curves, different levels of utility. If two curves intersected, the intersection point would represent a combination of goods with two different levels of utility --> impossible.
      (13 votes)
  • purple pi purple style avatar for user Raghav
    Don't the theories of diminishing marginal utility and monotonic preferences go against each other, in a sense? I mean, if a consumer keeps on consuming more and more of a particular good, then by law of DMU, he'll stop after a while, but according to monotonic preferences, he'll keep on and on consuming.
    (7 votes)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
    • blobby green style avatar for user Geoffrey.Transom
      No - diminishing marginal utility only means that the utility from the good decreases, not that it hits zero (which would be required for an unconstrained consumer to stop consuming that good).

      Consumption will only stop if marginal utility falls to (or below) zero, but that would violate monotonicity.

      If the utility function u(x) is monotonic, then u'(x) is always positive even though u''(x) is negative - that's the 'non-satiety axiom'. So u(x) is increasing in x, but at a decreasing rate.
      (8 votes)
  • male robot johnny style avatar for user Alex Newman
    What is an example of a third axis that could be used for a graph like this?
    (3 votes)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
  • male robot hal style avatar for user Enn
    Can a indifference curve intersect the x or y axis ?
    (4 votes)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
    • leafers ultimate style avatar for user Andris
      Yes, it can. There is actually an indifference curve in every single point in this coordinate system. This is just not so important, we are interested in the indifference curve which gives the highest utility.
      (3 votes)
  • piceratops ultimate style avatar for user worldwithoutmin
    Can indifference be area not curve?
    (3 votes)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
  • blobby green style avatar for user SYacob22
    Does it matter where you put f or c. Do you have to put the fruit on the x axis. Thanks.
    (3 votes)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
    • blobby green style avatar for user Subash Mahat
      it actually doesn't matter!! it is only how you plot the data in the graph!! for eg: you have 2 commodities say x and y!! if u keep them on the either axis the only thing that matters is how you plot the data! like you have a combination of 2 x commodities and 4 y commodities! the commodities can be placed any where like y commodity in x axis or x commodity in y axis or vice-versa !! you will plot 2 units of x commodity according to the way you have placed it in either x axis or y axis and it is the same with y commodity!
      (3 votes)
  • spunky sam blue style avatar for user ebracciale
    Why, if I am moving along the indifference curve (where I am supposed to be indifferent to change) is my marginal rate of substitution changing?
    (2 votes)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user
    • starky ultimate style avatar for user Geoff Ball
      Although you're indifferent to each bundle on the curve, you will have a different willingness to substitute each good at every point. For example, let's say you're indifferent between (1 pizza, 20 hamburgers) and (20 pizzas, 1 hamburger). At these two points, you are indifferent, but you will be much more willing to substitute a hamburger in the first bundle compared to the second.
      (4 votes)
  • blobby green style avatar for user aradhita
    What is a production possibility frontier? Is it related to indifference curve?
    (3 votes)
    Default Khan Academy avatar avatar for user

Video transcript

- [Narrator] In this video, we're going to explore the idea of an indifference curve. Indifference. Indifference curve. And what it is, is it describes all of the points, all of the combinations of things to which I am indifferent. In the past, we've thought about maximizing total utility. Now, we're going to talk about all of the combinations that essentially give us the same total utility. So, let's draw a graph that tells us all of the different combinations of two goods to which we are indifferent and like I've, we've mentioned before, we're focusing on two goods, because if we did three goods we would have to do it in three dimensions, and four goods would get very abstract. So, let's say in this axis, the vertical axis, this is going to be the quantity and we'll stay with the chocolate and the fruit trade-off. Those are the only two things that we consume. So, this is going to be the quantity of chocolate in bars and in the horizontal axis, this is going to be the quantity of fruit and this is going to be in pounds of fruit. And this will go, see this is 10, this is 20 this is 10, and this is 20 and this would be 15, 5, 5, and then 15. And let's say, let's say that right now, at some point, I am consuming 5 pounds of fruit per month and 15 bars of chocolate per month. So, that would put me right there. And if someone were to ask, "Sal, how would you feel, how would you feel if instead of that, instead of that, I were to give you, let's say, 10 bars of chocolate and 7 pounds, and 7 pounds of fruit?" And I would say, you know what, I'm indifferent. I wouldn't care whether I have, so this right over here is, I wouldn't care whether I have 15 bars of chocolate and 5 pounds of fruit or whether I have 10 bars of chocolate and 7 pounds of fruit. I am indifferent between these two. I have introspected on what I like and what I derive benefit and satisfaction out of, and I get the same total utility out of either of these, out of either of these points. So, both of these are on the same indifference curve and in general, I can plot all of the different combinations that give me the exact same total utility and it might look something like this. Let me try to draw it as neatly as possible. I'll do it in magenta. It might look something like this and then keep going all the way down like that. So, any point on this curve right over here, I'm indifferent relative to my current predicament of 15 bars and 5 pounds of chocolate. So, that is my indifference curve. Indifference. Indifference curve. Now, let's think about, so, obviously, if I go all over here, 20 pounds of fruit, and I don't know, that looks about 2 bars of chocolate, to me, the same utility based on my preferences, as where I started off with. So, someone just swapped everything out. I would just kind of, you know, shrug my shoulders and say yeah, no big deal. I wouldn't be happy. I wouldn't be sad. I am indifferent. Now, what about points down here? What about a point like this? Well, that is clearly not preferable because, for example, that point I just showed, I can show a point on the indifference curve where I am better off. For example, that point that I just did, that's 5 pounds of fruit and about 5 bars of chocolate, but assuming that the marginal benefit of more chocolate is positive, and the way I've drawn this, or the assumption is that it is, then, I'm obviously getting more benefit if I'm get even more chocolate per month. And so, anything down here, below the indifference curve, is not preferred. Not preferred. Preferred. And, using the same exact logic, anything out here, anything out here, well, that would be good because we're neutral between all of these points on the curve but this green point right over here, I have the same number of bars as a point on the curve, but I have a lot more pounds of fruit. It looks like I have 11 or 12 pounds of fruit. So, assuming that I'm getting marginal benefits from those incremental pounds of fruit, and we will make that assumption, then, this right over here, anything out here, is going to be preferred. So, this whole area is going to be preferred to everything on the curve. Preferred. And the whole area down here, is, obviously, we've not preferred to anything on the curve. And let me, just to show you this, not those points. So, all of this, and let me do that in a different color actually, 'cause our curve is purple, everything in blue is not preferred. Now, the last thing I want to think about in this video is what the slope of this indifference curve tells us. When I talk about the slope, and this is really kind of an idea out of Calculus, 'cause we're used to thinking about slopes of lines. So, if you give me a line like that, the slope is how much does my vertical axis change for every change in my horizontal axis? So, in a typical algebra class, that axis is your Y axis. That is your X axis. And when we think about slope, we say, okay, when I have a certain change in Y when I change in X by 1. So, we have something like this. So, when I change, I get a certain change in Y, the triangle means change in, delta, change in Y, when I get a certain change in X. And delta Y, the change in Y, over change in X is equal to the slope. But this is when it's a line and the slope isn't changing. At any point on this line, if I do the same ratio between the change in Y and the change in X, I'm going to get the same value. On a curve like this, the slope is constantly changing. So, what we really do, to figure out the slope exactly at a point, you can imagine, it's really the slope of the tangent line at that point. A line that would just touch at that point. So, for example, let's say that I draw a tangent line, I am going to draw my best attempt at drawing a tangent line and I'll do it in pink. Let's say I have a tangent line right from our starting predicament, just like that. And it looks something like that. It looks something like that. And so, right where we are now, exactly at this point, you know, if we veer away, it seems like our slope is changing. Matter of fact, it definitely is changing. It's becoming less steep as we go forward to the right. It's becoming more steep as we go to the left. But right there, the slope of the tangent line looks right like that or you can view that as the instantaneous slope right there. And we can measure the slope of the tangent line. We can say, look, if we want an extra, let's see, this looks like about, if we want an extra 2 pounds of fruit, how many bars are we going to have to give up? How many bars are we going to have to give up? Well, it looks like we're going to have to give up, based on the slope right over there, looks like we're going to have to give up 5 bars. So, this is 5 and this is 2. So, what is your change in, what is the slope here? The slope here, is going to be your change in bars, and I should actually say this is a negative right over there, it's going to be your change in bars, your change in chocolate bars, over your change in fruit. Over your change in fruit. And in this situation, it is -5 bars for every 2 fruit that you get. So, bars per fruit. Or you can say this is equal to -2.5 bars per fruit. So, it's essentially saying, exactly at that point, how are you willing to trade off bars for fruit? Exactly at that point, it's gonna change, as things change along this curve. But it's saying, exactly where you're sitting right now, you would be indifferent but it's only as you just slightly move for an extra drop of fruit, an extra ounce of fruit, not even a whole pound, you'd be willing to trade off 2 1/2 bars per fruit. And what this says, so you're willing to give up, since it's negative, you're giving up 2 1/2 bars of chocolate for every pound of fruit. Now, it's going to be different. Once you have a lot more fruit, you're going to be much less willing to give up bars of chocolate. Over here, you have a lot of bars and not a lot of fruit. So, you're willing to give up a lot of bars for fruit. Over here, if we go over here, the slope looks a little bit different. Over here, it is much flatter. So let me draw it in a color we haven't used yet. So, over here, the tangent line looks something like this. It looks something like this. And let's say, when you calculate it, in order to get, I don't know, this looks about 5 pounds of fruit, in order to get 5 pounds of fruit, you are going to have to give up 2 bars. So, once again, the slope is the change in the vertical axis over the change in the horizontal axis. So, over here, at this point, your change in bars over your change in fruit, is going to be, well, you're going to give up 2 bars, for every 5 fruit. Bars per fruit. So, this right over here, is -0.4. I'll say B for F. So over here, you're willing to give up much fewer bars for every incremental fruit. Up here, you were willing to give many bars away for every fruit and that makes sense. Over here, you had a lot of chocolate bars and not a lot of fruit. So, you were willing to give up more bars for your fruit. And over here, you have many fewer bars so you're much more resistant to giving up bars for fruit. But this number, how many bars you're willing to give up for an incremental fruit at any point here, or you could view it as a slope of the indifference curve, or the slope of a tangent line at that point of the indifference curve, this, right over here is called our marginal rate of substitution. Marginal rate of substitution. It's a very fancy word but all it's really saying is how much you're willing to give up of the vertical axis for an increment of the horizontal axis. Right at that point, and it changes, as soon as you move, because this is a curve, it changes a little bit, but right at that point, for a super super small amount, how many bars are you willing to give up for fruit? And obviously, it changes as we go along this indifference curve.