If you're seeing this message, it means we're having trouble loading external resources on our website.

If you're behind a web filter, please make sure that the domains *.kastatic.org and *.kasandbox.org are unblocked.

Main content
Current time:0:00Total duration:6:50
AP.MICRO:
MKT‑1 (EU)
,
MKT‑1.A (LO)
,
MKT‑1.A.1 (EK)

Video transcript

when you think about what the field of economics is about it is quite daunting an economy is made up of millions or even billions of actors organized in incredibly complex ways right then this is complex real world and each of the actors human beings or organizations these are incredibly complex a human brain I can't predict what you're going to do the next second much less what you're going to do the next day or the next year and imagine trying to make insights about what millions or billions of people will do but the field of economics has borrowed an idea from other fields so for example in chemistry chemists have tried to understand at a high level well how do molecules in a container behave let's say molecules of gas well you could imagine if you have a container here with trillions upon trillions of molecules this is incredibly complex but by making some simplifying assumptions about the type of interactions these particles will have or don't have they can come up with models like the ideal gas law which you might be familiar with or not from your chemistry class that relates the pressure to the volume to the number of particles you have to the actual temperature and so this right over here where you're taking something that's hairy and complex and making simplifying assumptions to help you understand it this thing right over here is a model and this is in other fields as well sometimes it's not an equation sometimes it might be a simpler organism for example in biology human beings are incredibly complex organisms and not only are they incredibly complex but certain forms of experimentation would also feel fairly unethical to our modern moral ethos and so what do biologists do well they make simplifying assumptions or they pair down they say okay we can't do that study on human beings but maybe we can simplify the problem by looking at simpler organisms maybe you can look at an individual cell right over here maybe you can look at things like fruit flies which are famous in their study in the study of genetics maybe you can even look at fairly complex organisms even a mouse is a very complex thing but it's still simpler than a human being and at least to our modern ethics we're willing to do certain things to mice that we aren't willing to do to human beings and so that's why in a biological context you will hear people talk about things like a mouse model where they will test the drug on a mouse or try to understand how something happens in a mouse and then say well that's pretty good indication that might be happening to human beings in fact when they do drug trials in medicine they often will do it on mice first and when they have good confidence that it works there and that it's fairly safe only then will they start to do the experiments on human beings well economists are doing the same thing even before the advent of computers and models economists make simplifying assumptions assumptions like all of the actors in an economy are rational which we already know is not exactly true I'm not always rational and I definitely know people who aren't always rational they're simplifying assumptions that all of the people in an economy have the same access to information or that they all even have perfect information which we also know isn't necessarily true in a real economy so depending on the model there going to be these simplifying assumptions that take this large complex real world thing and try to break it down into simple equations or lines or charts we have models early on in our economic study we will see things like the production possibility frontier where it assumes that you're only trading off between two things and everything else is equal this notion of ceteris ceteris paribus which means all things equal in a real world you're not going to be able to say hey let's just pick between these two things and then hold everything else equal there's hundreds or thousands or millions of variables are operating but if you want to make a model maybe we can make these assumptions same thing with famous price equilibria that we're going to study later on where you have supply and demand and then you have these notions of equilibrium prices and quantities these also make similar types of assumptions about rational actors and perfect information and these economic models can be very useful and that's why most of your study in a first-year economics course is of these models now with that said you should also take them with a grain of salt and you shouldn't just accept them as the absolute description of reality in fact that's when economic models can get dangerous you always have to be conscientious of what are those assumptions you made in fact Nobel Prizes have been won in economics by revisiting some simplifying assumptions and coming up with new models the other difficulty about economics is it's hard to test it in as absolute a way definitely as something like chemistry or physics but even in biology where you're dealing with similarly complex the human body and an economy these are both extremely complex systems if I want to see in medicine whether a certain medication works I can do a clinical trial I could take hundreds or thousands of people and give maybe half of them the drug and I could try to control for a bunch of different variables but in economics you can't take a thousand different economies that look very similar in what you think matters and then apply some type of economic prescription to half of them and then see what happens to see whether your model is exactly true or whether your prescription for what makes an economy grow faster actually work and so the big takeaway models are valuable across the various Sciences including in economics but economics straddles between the social science and the sciences like chemistry or physics because you can't run experiments in the same way and we often make simplifying assumptions that even though we know aren't exactly true they're the only way that we're able to make sense of an incredibly complex real world
AP® is a registered trademark of the College Board, which has not reviewed this resource.